Revista Electrónica de Investigación Educativa
Vol. 11, No. 2, 2009
Increase in Schooling of Mexico’s Economically Active
Population and Its Effect on Employment
Status and Income, 1992-20041
María de Ibarrola
mdei@prodigy.net.mx
Departamento de Investigaciones Educativas
Centro de Investigación y de Estudios Avanzados
Instituto Politécnico Nacional
Calzada de los Tenorios 235
Colonia Granjas Coapa, 14330
México, D.F., México
(Received: June 3, 2009; accepted for publishing: July 23, 2009)
Abstract
This paper presents some effects of the remarkable increase in schooling in
Mexico on the employment status of the country’s non-agricultural, economically-active
population (EAP) between the ages of 24 and 60. We analyze
the distribution of this population by categories, including the level of schooling
attained, hourly earnings and participation in one of the country’s five
different labor sectors: two informal (self-employed workers and managers of
informal microenterprises) and three formal (public sector, companies in the
industrial sector, and service sector companies). Data from 1992 to 2004 are
compared. The results derive from a database developed for Mexico as part of
several national studies conducted by the Information System on Educational
Trends in Latin America (SITEAL for its acronym in Spanish),
based on the National Survey of Income-Expenditure.
Keywords: Academic achievement, educational attainment, income, labor
market.
Introduction
The increase in schooling in Mexico has been one of the most impressive educational
achievements in the country, as an analysis of historical data easily demonstrates,
and as has been registered by some researchers (Mercado and Planas, 2005). The
effects of this increase in the educational level of the economically active
population (EAP) in the country are evident. The latest
data from the Institute of Statistics and Geography (INEGI—acronym
in Spanish, n.d.) indicate that average years of schooling of the country’s
EAP rose from 6.8 in 1992 to 8.4 in 2004, and reached
9.1 years of school in 2009.
Despite this there are few studies drawn from national statistics
that would allow a systematized and longitudinal analysis of the impact of this
increase on the labor distribution of the EAP in the country,
according to differences in formality or informality among the occupational
sectors as well as the differences in income that result from this double condition.
In 2006, UNESCO’s Information System on Educational
Trends in Latin America (SITEAL--acronym in Spanish, n.d.)
systematized a series of common indicators on schooling, average hourly income,
age, sex and size of locality, based on five occupational sectors—two
informal and three formal—in which the EAP of several
countries is pinpointed. In order to facilitate comparison, data were obtained
from the National Survey of Household Income and Expenditures or its
equivalent for the years 1992, 1996, 2002 and 2004. The present analysis was
built based on a selection of these data for Mexico.2
The complex relationship between educational level and work
In a recently published textbook, Dr. Martin Carnoy (2006) briefly and simply
describes the history of the relationships between education and work and how
economists have conceived them. It is surprising that the perception and conceptualization
of the differences and inequalities between workers with regard to their education,
skills and abilities—despite having been identified by many classic authors,
from Adam Smith on—was only taken up again theoretically
as recently as the middle of the last century with the theory of human capital,
a term coined so successfully by Theodore Schultz.3
With this theory it has been common to reduce human capital to years of schooling
attained, which is measured in terms of completed grade levels. Research in
this area has found some consistent large-scale results; for example, the positive
correlations between higher educational levels in the workforce of a country
and its productivity; the fact that higher educational levels are positively
correlated to higher incomes and job positions, that is, the proportionately
higher rates of return that are generated by schooling, not including its direct
and indirect costs. These macro results have, with some impunity, transformed
the correlation into causality, reinforcing the common-sense belief about the
economic benefits of education.
Various researchers—educational economists and educational sociologists—have
questioned this mechanistic vision (Levin and Kelley, 1994). Gary Becker (1964,
p. 17) states that “education and training are the most important investment
in human capital”; however, he also recognizes the influence of the family
in the formation of the worker as well as the contribution made to the worker’s
development by job-site learning and training.
A line of research initiated in 1986 (Hanushek, 1986; Hanushek and Woesman,
2007) proposes distinguishing between quality of education and schooling.
It is not the hours spent “seat-warming” in a classroom that influence
economic development, but knowledge and skills, which can indeed be developed
in school, but which can also be fostered by the family, peers and culture.
Schools in and of themselves are not the answer. Other factors have a significant
impact on earnings and growth, on economic institutions, the openness of the
economy, property systems, and so on. Without them, education and skills will
not have the desired impact on economic performance.
An important part of the arguments and premises that take issue with human capital
theory relate to the theory of reproduction. The now classic texts of Baudelot
and Establet (1975) and of Bourdieu and Passeron (1964) focus on the unequal
distribution of opportunities of access to education, which is closely correlated
to preexisting socioeconomic inequalities. Recent studies posit that the increase
in educational opportunities has shifted the effects of socioeconomic inequalities
onto areas internal to schooling: student failure; delays that result in students
pursuing grade levels or degrees at more advanced ages; the possibilities of
finishing each academic cycle in the allotted time; grades; and the type of
educational institution to which the student has access, among other aspects
that continue to demonstrate such correlations (Schwartzman, 2004; Tenti and
Cervini, 2004).
Other authors focus on the limitations of the labor market: education does not
create jobs, they argue, and those who attain relatively higher levels of schooling
can, if anything, go to the front of the waiting line for employment; they will
be the last to lose their jobs, although they may possibly experience wage reductions,
or perhaps become underemployed or join the ranks of unemployed college graduates
and suffer the “devaluation” of their educational degrees in an
increasingly inflationary degree market (National Association of Universities
and Institutions of Higher Education [ANUIES, acronym
in Spanish], 2003; Muñoz Izquierdo, 2001; Carnoy, 2005).
Income, meanwhile, does not depend on the worker’s educational level,
but on his/her position in the job market and in the company organization (Levin
and Nelly, 1994). As various authors have demonstrated, including Muñoz
Izquierdo (1996), Hualde and Serrano (2005) and Planas (2008), among others,
the role education plays in work, employment or income varies according to the
economic period in question, the geographical region, the economic sector, the
individual’s gender and age and even the history and culture of the companies
themselves.
In a specific job space, the same college degree does not guarantee the same
high salary or better job position to all those who hold it (De Ibarrola and
Reynaga, 1983), nor does a degree from a technical school ensure getting a job
related to the field of studies (De Ibarrola, 1994; National Technical and Vocational
Education School [Conalep, acronym in Spanish], 2006). Moreover, to the extent
that schooling is distributed more evenly among the population, as is the case
with elementary and junior high school, it ceases to be a causal variable of
differences in income and job position, at least in well-defined sectors of
the labor market (De Ibarrola, 2004a).
Labor markets in Mexico
Most Mexican researchers who analyze the relationship between educational level
and employment concur in referring to job markets and contend that
their heterogeneous character plays an important role in the nature of the relationships
established between said markets and schooling (Reynaga, 2003). Due to limitations
of space for this article, aspects of formality or informality and other characterizations
of the heterogeneous and unequal structure of labor markets in Mexico are not
described, as they have been posited and discussed in depth in other studies
(De Ibarrola, 1988, 1994, 2004a, 2004b).
In this paper we accept the general distinction of heterogeneity between formal
and informal sector, and the five occupational sectors: two informal
sectors (self-employed and microenterprises that employ less than five workers)
and three formal sectors (public sector, large companies in the industrial sector
and large companies in the service sector) that are identified by the available
database and whose operational definition respects the main criteria of the
authors that are identified in the above-cited studies. It should be noted that
it is not the aim of this paper to explain the political and economic factors
that contextualize and determine said heterogeneity in countries like Mexico,
or that provide the framework for the relationship between schooling and employment
in the country.
The objective of this article is simple and rather limited:
it seeks to provide national statistical data showing how the increase in schooling
of the economically active population in Mexico between1992 and 2004 was distributed
between the various occupational sectors, defined according to their formality
or informality in the labor market, and the differences in income resulting
from the level of schooling attained and the work sector in which the individual
is employed.4
Two theoretical approaches support the importance of the objective of this article.
The first contends that the country’s increase in schooling is not derived
from a rational planning based on the availability of jobs for different types
of training, nor does it respond to the qualification requirements for (generic)
development. The increase in schooling has been a product of the tensions and
contradictions between governmental proposals, aimed in great measure at boosting
education in accordance with a (certain) vision of the development needs of
the country or the (supposed) demands of the labor market; of the limited vision
of labor sectors; of the demands and aspirations of young people and their families;
and of the possibilities of educational institutions in a context characterized
by the existence of heterogeneous and unequal labor markets (De Ibarrola, 2009).
This is not to ignore the fact that educational opportunities, particularly
following completion of compulsory education, are clearly insufficient.
The second approach divides interpretations of the effects of increased schooling
on earnings and employment into two main arguments:
a) The first, which is related particularly to the growth of higher education,
attributes the failure of college graduates to find employment in professional
positions commensurate with their level of schooling to the dysfunctionality
of the educational system (ANUIES, 2003).
b) The second postulates that the increase in schooling (at all levels) has
had a significant supply effect by creating an increasingly better-educated
labor force that is expressed as follows: “the increase in education has
been extended to all employment categories as a result of the strong effect
of educational supply, relatively independent of a parallel development of job
categories” (Béduwé and Planas, 2002, p. 58). The educated
population is spread throughout all occupational sectors and its higher levels
of schooling have been rewarded with the higher relative earnings that the labor
market offers to those with relatively higher educational levels (Béduwé
and Planas, 2002; Flores and Román, 2005; Planas, Román, Flores
and De Ibarrola, 2007).
In none of these cases do the authors analyze the heterogeneity of labor markets.
The data analyzed here, although based on highly aggregated categories, provide
results that take into account important differences between occupational sectors,
thus offering new possibilities for understanding the impact that the growth
in education has had on the employment and earnings attained by the population.
Increase in the educational level of the EAP and
decrease in employment formality
Tables I and II offer two seemingly contradictory types of basic data:
a) Table I shows the remarkable increase in the educational level of the economically
active population in the period under consideration, particularly the decrease
in the EAP that has only achieved a fifth grade education,
and the increase in the EAP with higher education.
Table I. Percentage distribution of schooling for the total
EAP
between 25 and 60 years of age
b) In Table II we can observe a slight decrease in the formal sector, particularly in favor of self-employed workers, as well as greater growth in the public sector than in large corporations of the secondary and service sectors.
Table II. Distribution of the EAP between
the informal and formal
labor sectors 1992-2004
Educational level and insertion in labor market sectors
Table III analyzes the distribution by occupational sectors of the population
with incomplete elementary level schooling,5
a demographic which decreased 13.2 percentage points for the total economy during
the period under consideration.
Table III. Percentage of the EAP that
did not complete elementary education
by occupational sector
The EAP with this low educational profile decreased by
just half a percentage point (-0.5) among the self-employed and workers in the
public sector (-0.7). However, it declined significantly among employees and
employers in companies with less than five workers, followed by workers in large
corporations in the secondary and service sectors.
Meanwhile, as can be observed in Table IV, the labor force with more than thirteen
years of schooling—which rose 8.8 percentage points during the period—increased
mainly in the formal service sector and only slightly among the self-employed.
However, the growth in workers with higher education in informal micro-enterprises
was greater than that in the public sector and almost equal to that in the formal
industrial sector. Large corporations in the tertiary sector continued to be
the biggest employers of the population with more than thirteen years of schooling.
Table IV. Percentage of the EAP with
13 or more years of education
by occupational sector
It should be noted—although the data is not displayed thus in the charts—that
the informal sector in 1992 comprised 33.1% of the total and 43.8% of the EAP
with incomplete elementary level schooling, but only 15.3% of the labor force
with higher education. By contrast, during the same year, the formal sector
contained 65.4% of the total EAP, and while it included
56.2% of the population without an elementary education, it also concentrated
84.4% of the economically active population with higher education. However,
by 2004 the distribution had changed, in particular due to the increase in workers
with higher education in the informal sector, which eventually captured 19.5%
of the work force with thirteen or more years of schooling.
In both years, employees with the higher level of schooling were concentrated
in large corporations in the service sector, but this concentration declined
from 63.2% to 53.1% during the period, while the public sector nearly tripled
its proportion of workers with more than thirteen years of schooling.
Variation in hourly earnings according to economic sector
As indicated in Table V, income is significantly affected by the economic sector
in which the worker is employed. In the years for which we have information,
the income of workers in the informal sector represents only between 0.64 and
0.68 of the national average for income for those dates, while the incomes of
those in the formal sector were between 1.23 and 1.29 times the average. Those
with the lowest earnings were self-employed,6
whose income did not amount to even a fifth of the national average. In contrast,
those who surpassed the average were, in first place, employees of the service
sector, followed by workers in the public sector.
Table V. Distribution of hourly earnings by sector of the economy
and income
gap () in relation to the average hourly income of the total
It is interesting to note that formal secondary sector workers saw an increase
in the gap between their earnings and the average formal sector earnings: in
2004 their income was lower than the overall average, approaching that of employees
and employers of informal microenterprises.
Moreover, those who most increased their income were public sector workers,
who by 2004 were, on average, the highest paid. This is due, without a doubt,
to all of the policies implemented to support the poorest sectors of the country;
the self-employed tripled their meager income during the period, although they
continue to be—by definition—the workers with lowest earnings.
The role of schooling
The distribution of hourly earnings by schooling attained is highly significant:
Table VI shows a steady increase in average earnings as the level of schooling
attained rises. The income difference between those that have higher education
and those who failed to complete their primary education is very high in the
two years indicated: 4.5 times higher earnings for the college educated group
in 1992, although in 2004 the difference fell to 3.9. The income difference
between those with higher education and the level of schooling immediately below
them, a 10th to 12th grade education, is almost double for the college educated:
1.83 times higher in 2004 and in 1992, 1.6 times higher.
Table VI. Distribution of hourly earnings by educational level
attained and
income gap () in relation to the overall average (2004 Mexican pesos)
Impact of schooling and
occupational sector on income
It is also clear that the occupational sector in which the EAP
is employed affects the income gap between those with higher education and those
who barely finished their elementary education, as can be observed in Table
VII.
Table VII. Distribution
of hourly earnings by economic sector and income gap ()
in relation to the average of the total of the group with
13 or more years of schooling (2004 Mexican pesos)
The data in Table VII show that
the average income of workers with thirteen years or more of schooling varies
significantly depending on the occupational sector. In 1992 workers in large
corporations in the secondary sector far outperformed the category average,
whereas the self-employed, despite having the same high level of education,
were the farthest from the group’s average income, earning 21.6 times
less than workers in the industrial sector. By 2004, this gap was reduced by
almost two thirds. Throughout the period, however, the gap in income compared
with the average also increased for those working in microenterprises in the
informal sector and, in particular, for those working in large corporations
in the secondary sector, as they clearly lost the big advantage they had had
with respect to workers in the other sectors.
The figures also show a significant increase in salary for workers in the public
sector, although proportional to their lower earnings in relation to those of
the other occupational sectors. Surprisingly, the greatest relative increase
during the period went to the self-employed.
In Table VIII income by occupational sector for those who only studied up to
the fifth grade of elementary school is analyzed, with the following results:
Table VIII. Hourly
income distribution by economic sector and income gap ()
in relation to the average of the total for the group with less than 5 years
of
elementary school education (2004 Mexican pesos).
There is a marked contrast between
workers employed by large corporations in the service sector (the highest earners)
and the self-employed (the lowest earners). The former earned 4.42 times more
in 1992, while in 2004 their income was 3.21 times higher, due to the reduction
in income gap for corporations in the tertiary sector. Once again we can observe
the wage increase for workers in the public sector. However, the income gap
between occupational sectors for those with this low educational level was not
as pronounced in either of the two years studied as was observed for the group
who had some higher education.
Table IX examines the income gap between those with higher or lower levels of
schooling within each occupational sector, which proves to be the source of
the most significant gap, although it varies between sectors and throughout
the period under consideration. The largest gap occurred in large companies
in the secondary sector during 1992, when workers with more than thirteen years
of schooling employed in said sector earned 6.8 times the income of those in
the same sector with no more than five years of schooling. In the public sector
those with the highest educational levels earned 4.18 times more than those
with the least schooling. By 2004, the size of the gap was reduced by almost
half in all of the sectors, particularly in large corporations in the industrial
sector, although it widened in large companies in the service sector and among
the self-employed (who in 1992 earned even less than those who did not finish
elementary school).
Table IX. Income gap
between those with the most schooling
(13 years or more) and those with the least (5 years or less), by occupational
sector in 1992 and 2004
Summary and Conclusions
This paper just touches a very small piece of the surface of the complex and
multidimensional puzzle that is the relationship between education and work
in Mexico.
Many facets were not analyzed here: the younger populace in the country, workers
in the primary sector, gender impact, the size of localities, to mention a few.
We also did not address the fluctuations of the economy: inflation reached 457%
in the period under consideration; between 1994 and 1995 in particular, the
economic crisis was brutal, with a currency devaluation of 100% in 1994. By
1999 a recovery was underway that was reflected in the better wages recorded
for 2004 in all occupational sectors. However, starting in 2007 a new crisis
emerged that is now recognized as far worse than the previous one. The dramatic
fall of the gross domestic product (GDP), a more severe
recession than that of 1994-1995, the serious loss of formal jobs, the decline
of economic activity in all sectors and in earnings, together with the rise
in poverty (Acosta, 2009), mark a new economic period that clearly limits the
scope of the data analyzed here to a very specific period and demonstrates the
great sensitivity of income to the fluctuations of the economy.
It is, therefore, useful to highlight the contributions of this study:
1) The increase in schooling in the country is undeniable, reflected
in the increasingly higher levels of average schooling of the economically active
population between 25 and 60 years of age from 1992 to 2004, although most of
the active population in this age group (60%) is still below the now compulsory
basic educational level.7
Paradoxically, despite the increase in schooling, the possibility of integration/insertion
in the formal sector of the economy decreased slightly.
2) The differences in education among the population tend to correlate with
the different sectors of the economy identified in this paper: those with less
than five years of schooling tend to be concentrated in the informal sector
among the self-employed and those who achieved thirteen or more years of schooling
in large tertiary sector corporations and in the public sector. But there are
individuals with higher and lower levels of education in all the occupational
sectors, and the increase in schooling is discernible in all of them, even slightly
modifying the proportional distribution among them.
3) In all occupational sectors, those with higher educational levels have significantly
higher average incomes than those with less schooling. (Self-employed individuals
with higher education in 1992 comprise the one exception to this trend.) Therefore,
the increase in schooling is remunerated within all occupational sectors.
4) The difference in income for those with the same level of schooling can be
very high between occupational sectors, particularly for those who have higher
education. Among those with no more than five years of schooling the differences
are not so great.
5) Throughout the period under consideration the income gap between those with
less and those with more schooling tended to decrease. One might conclude that
the increase in the average schooling of the population had a positive effect
on reducing income inequalities; but the fluctuations encountered do not allow
us to infer that we are already facing a trend, especially if one takes into
account more recent economic data.
6) The proportion of the EAP with little schooling decreased
in all occupational sectors, although most significantly in large companies
in the industrial as well as the service sector, which impose academic requirements
on their prospective employees, demanding increasingly better educated workers.
In the public sector, union policies most likely impede calls for higher academic
requirements for the same type of job positions. One of the characteristics
of the informal sector is precisely that there are no educational prerequisites
for joining it.
7) For its part, the EAP with higher education increased
in all sectors and its weight in percentage terms shifted slightly toward the
informal occupational sectors. Without a doubt, a possible explanation could
be the dysfunctionality of the schooling achieved, since 20% of those with the
highest educational level were actually unable to find jobs in the best occupational
sectors. But the fact that they are spread out in other sectors—in particular
among the ranks of the self-employed and microenterprises—should not preclude
their obtainment of higher incomes than those with less schooling. These results
could be explained as an indication of the emergence of new sources of employment
and new professions generated by those with high levels of schooling, but which
fall into the informal sector of the economy. A more complete analysis would
require a review of the performance of the rate of return on the investment
in education.
8) The sector comprising large industrial companies, despite the rise in educational
level of its employees, was proportionally the most affected throughout the
period in question. The sector continued to attract workers with thirteen or
more years of schooling, despite the fact that their income advantage, compared
with workers with the same educational level in other sectors, decreased markedly.
This could be an indication that the sector has not managed to fully apply its
employees’ higher levels of knowledge to its competitiveness strategies.
It is also the sector that has been hardest hit by trade liberalization in the
country.
9) Large companies in the service sector boasted the largest concentration of
the EAP with higher education for both of the years under
consideration, although their share of highly educated workers declined during
the period, while the public and informal sectors saw corresponding increases
in their numbers of highly schooled workers. The income advantage of workers
in this type of large corporation increased. These are companies that tout the
need for higher educational levels in view of the new knowledge economy, an
approach that many of them are implementing (Planas, 2008), notwithstanding
that even so they are not able to accommodate all the available workers with
higher education.
10) During the period analyzed, the public sector had the greatest relative
increase in terms of the number of workers that it incorporated and in the incorporation
of the EAP with more schooling as well as in terms of
the wage increase of its labor force. Interestingly, at the national level,
based on highly aggregated data, two important polices relating to employees
in the public education sector can be observed: the requirement of a bachelor’s
degree starting in 1984 and the salary adjustments granted to teachers in the
national educational system, who comprise the occupational group with the greatest
salary increase during the last decade (Flores and Román, 2005).
The analyzed data confirm on a macro scale the theoretical warnings about the
limits that heterogeneous occupational sectors—in this case---impose on
schooling per se as a factor of direct impact on labor placement and income,
as was posited at the outset of this study and about which other research has
been conducted. At the same time, we can discern three situations that are important
for the study of the relationship between schooling and work, all three of which
must be examined more deeply in the double context of the heterogeneity of the
country’s labor markets and the rise in educational levels: a) the increase
in schooling in all sectors, b) the possible reduction of income inequality
that is attributable to widely varying educational levels as well as to the
disparities between occupational sectors, to the extent that inequalities of
educational level decrease, and, c) the potential positive effects of schooling
on productivity and income in the different sectors.
Independently of the very poor quality of the schooling attained, as currently
measured and subsequently denounced in the results of international assessments,
the increased presence of a more highly educated population in the informal
sectors allows us to affirm that workers with more than thirteen years of schooling
earn higher average income than those with less education. The increase in the
level of schooling over time would translate into: a) improved skills and higher
levels of knowledge, which in turn would lead to new beneficiaries of education;
b) landing those job positions that are characterized by being the best paid
(presumably because they require higher levels of knowledge); c) better job
performance, or, alternatively, d) the creation of new and more productive jobs,
even in the most disadvantaged sectors.
On the other hand, this situation could also denote, as others have pointed
out (Muñoz, 1996), the shifting of selectivity towards other levels and
its rigorous implementation in the formal occupational sectors. Nevertheless,
a better understanding of its characteristics and significance is essential.
Schooling per se clearly has not solved the problems of the country’s
economic growth or of the heterogeneity of the job markets. But the increase
in schooling operates within the unequal occupational sectors in ways and with
effects that make it imperative that it be analyzed more rigorously and in greater
depth.
References
Acosta, C. (2009, 31 de julio). Vamos bien en materia económica.
Retrieved October 8, 2009, from http://www.proceso.com.mx/noticias_articulo.php?articulo=71937
Asociación Nacional de Universidades e Instituciones de Educación
Superior. (2003). Mercado laboral de profesionistas en México
(4 vols.). México: Author.
Baudelot, C. y Establet, R. (1975). La escuela capitalista en Francia.
Mexico: Siglo XXI Editores.
Becker, G. S (1964). Human capital. A theoretical and empirical Analysis
with special reference to education. Chicago: The University of Chicago
Press.
Béduwé C. y Planas, J. (2002). Expansión educativa
y mercado de trabajo. Estudio comparativo realizado en cinco países europeos:
Alemania, España, Francia, Italia, Reino Unido, con referencia a los
Estados Unidos (Informe final de un proyecto financiado por el Programa
Marco de Investigaciones y Desarrollos de la Unión Europea: Ministerio
de trabajos y asuntos sociales). Madrid: Instituto Nacional de las Cualificaciones
de Madrid.
Bourdieu, P. y Passeron, J. C. (1964). Los herederos. Los estudiantes y
la cultural. Mexico: Siglo XXI Editores.
Carnoy, M. (2005). The economics of education. Unpublished document.
Universitat Oberta de Cataluña, Barcelona.
Colegio Nacional de Educación Profesional Técnica. (2006). Seguimiento
de egresados. Informe nacional Encuesta 2001-2004 y 2002-2005. México:
Secretaría de Educación Pública-Colegio Nacional de Educación
Profesional Técnica-RVoxPsolutions.
De Ibarrola, M. (1988). Hacia una re conceptualización de las relaciones
entre el mundo de la educación y el mundo del trabajo en América
Latina. Revista Latinoamericana de Estudios Educativos, 2,
9-64.
De Ibarrola, M. (1994). Escuela y trabajo en el sector agropecuario en México.
México: Centro de Investigación y Estudios Avanzados del IPN-Instituto
José María Luís Mora-Porrúa-Facultad Latinoamericana
de Ciencias Sociales.
De Ibarrola, M. (Dir. y Coord). (2004a). Escuela, capacitación y
aprendizaje. La formación de los jóvenes para el trabajo en una
ciudad en transición. Montevideo, Uruguay: Organización Internacional
del Trabajo, Cinterfor.
De Ibarrola, M. (2004b). Paradojas recientes de la educación frente
al mercado de trabajo y la inserción social. Buenos Aires: Instituto
Internacional de Planeamiento de la Educación-RedEtis-ides ( Tendencias
y debates 1).
De Ibarrola, M. (2006). El incremento de la escolaridad en México
y sus efectos sobre el mercado de trabajo en México, 1992-2004.
Informe del caso mexicano. Documento no publicado, SITEAL/UNESCO-IIPE/OEI.
De Ibarrola, M. (en prensa). Priorité a la formation scolaire pour le
travail au Méxique. Tensions et contradictions entre l’Etat, les
secteurs professionnels et les étudiants. Formation Emploi: Revue
Francaise des Sciences Sociales, 108.
De Ibarrola, M. y Reynaga Obregón, S. (1983). Estructura de producción,
mercado de trabajo y escolaridad en México. Revista Latinoamericana
de Estudios Educativos, 13 (3), 11-83.
Flores Elizondo, R. y Román, L. I. (2005). La retribución
de la expansión educativa en el empleo: un análisis sobre México
comparado con la Unión Europea (Reporte de trabajo). Documento no
publicado.
Hanushek, E. A. (1986). The economics of schooling: production and efficiency
in public schools. Journal of Economic Literature, 24, 141-1177.
Hanushek, E. y Wößmann, L. (2007). The role of education quality
in economic growth (Documento de trabajo 4122). Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Hualde, A. y Serrano, A. (2005).
La calidad del empleo de asalariados con educación superior en Tijuana
y Monterrey. Revista Mexicana de Investigación Educativa, 10,
345- 374.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Geografía. (s.f.). Consulta
de resultados. Numeralia. Consultado el 8 de octubre de 2009 en:
http://www.inegi.org.mx/est/contenidos/espanol/proyectos/integracion/inegi324.asp?s=est&c=11722
Levin, H. M y Kelley, C. (1994). Can education do it alone? Economics of
Education Review, 13 (2), 97-108.
Mercado, A. y Planas, J. (2005). Evolución del nivel de estudios de la
oferta de trabajo en México. Una comparación con la Unión
Europea. Revista Mexicana de Investigación Educativa, 10(25),
315- 343.
Muñoz Izquierdo, C. (1996). Diferenciación institucional de
la educación superior y mercado de trabajo. Seguimiento de egresados
de diferentes instituciones a partir de las universidades de origen y de las
empresas en que trabajan. México: Asociación Nacional de
Universidades e Instituciones de Educación Superior.
Muñoz Izquierdo, C. (2001). Implicaciones de la escolaridad en la
calidad del empleo en México. México: Universidad Iberoamericana-UNICEF-Cinterfor-Colegio
Nacional de Educación Profesional Técnica.
Planas, J., Mercado, A., Román, I., Flores, R. y De Ibarrola, M. (2007,
enero). Expansión educativa y mercado de trabajo en México,
una comparación con la Unión Europea y Estados Unidos (Reporte
de trabajo). Documento no publicado, Universidad de Guadalajara-ITESO-Cinvestav-Universitat
Autònoma de Barcelona-Université de Toulouse CNAM
Paris.
Planas, J. (2008). El comportamiento de los empleadores mexicanos frente al
crecimiento de la educación. Revista de Educación Superior,
37 (146), 11-40.
Reynaga Obregón, S. (Coord. de Vol.). (2003). La investigación
educativa en México, 1992-2002: Vol. 6. Educación, trabajo, ciencia
y tecnología. México: Consejo Mexicano de Investigación
Educativa.
Schwartzman, S. (2004). Acceso y retrasos en la educación en América
Latina (Serie Debates, No. 1: Equidad en el acceso y la permanencia en
el sistema educativo). Buenos Aires: Sistemas de Información de Tendencias
Educativas en América Latina Consultado el 8 de octubre de 2009 en:
http://www.siteal.iipe-oei.org/modulos/DebatesV1/upload//deb_23/art_13/ART_SimonSchwartzman.pdf
Sistema de Información y Tendencias Educativas en América Latina
(s.f.). Base de datos. Consultado el 8 de octubre de 2009, en: http://www.siteal.org/basededatos/basededatos1.asp
Tenti, E. y Cervini, R. (2004). Notas sobre la masificación de la
escolarización en seis países de América Latina. (Serie:
Debates, No. 1: Equidad en el acceso y la permanencia en el sistema educativo).
Buenos Aires: Sistemas de Información de Tendencias Educativas en América
Latina Consultado el 8 de octubre de 2009 en: http://www.siteal.iipe-oei.org/modulos/DebatesV1/upload//deb_23/art_15/ART_Cervini-Tenti.pdf
1Excerpts
from the Chapter of the Report by Country, unpublished: De Ibarrola, María.
El caso mexicano [The Mexican Case], prepared under contract with SITEAL,
UNESCO-IIPE, OEI (February
2006). Translator’s Note: SITEAL is the Spanish
acronym for the Information System on Educational Trends in Latin America, which
is under the auspices of the International Institute of Educational Planning
(IIPE, acronym in Spanish) of UNESCO
and the Organization of Iberian-American States (OEI,
acronym in Spanish).
2I was asked to draw up the report on Mexico in relation to education and labor markets (De Ibarrola, 2006). It should be noted that the database had some important limitations: it did not include the EAP in the agricultural sector nor workers less than 24 years old. Categories for studying the level of schooling attained, as can be seen in the corresponding section, were highly aggregated, but the importance of the database consisted in the possibility it offered for analyzing five different sectors of the economy, which are described later.
3The first translation into Spanish [of Schultz’ book], Valor económico de la educación (The Economic Value of Education), was issued by UTEHA publishing house (Barcelona) in 1968.
4In this regard, and given the nature of the data, the statistical analyzes are based on percentage distributions and in particular on the differences in earnings for each of the different categories.
5We analyzed only the most extreme categories of educational levels: those who received only five years of schooling or less, and those who had at least one year of higher education (thirteen years or more).
6It should be remembered that a criterion for identifying the self-employed was that their hourly earnings be 30% lower in the distribution of hourly earnings consisting solely of self-employed workers 2.7.
7Translator’s
note: Compulsory education in Mexico, what is known as “educación
básica” is elementary and junior high school, grades 1 through
9, and usually also requires two to three years of preschool as well.
Please cite the source as:
De Ibarrola, M. (2009). Increase
in schooling of Mexico’s economically active population and its effect
on employment status and income, 1992-2004. Revista Electrónica de
Investigación Educativa, 11(2). Retrieved month, day, year,
from http://redie.uabc.mx/vol11no2/contents-deibarrola.html